GAME THEORY: AN APPLICATION IN ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAVIOUR
WRITTEN BY: ANDY PAN
Game Theory: An Application in Organizational Behaviour
A hypothetical but original concept by Andy Pan
What is Game Theory?
Game Theory is a mathematical concept that was made popular by actor, Russell Crowe, in the hit film “A Beautiful Mind” that was screened in 2002. Some of us might have even studied this particularly interesting theory while in school. While some of us may even be practicing and/or applying it right now at work without us knowing. It is a theory that can hide it conspicuous head in the everyday things that we do, from strategic planning to even the making of simple daily choices. So what exactly is Game Theory?
A Game Theory can be defined as a means of analyzing strategic actions that, more often than not, result from the consideration of the expected behaviour of others; or simply, the decisions that is made by one, taking into account the response from a would-be affected party by one’s decision. Got it? I know this sounds a little confusing but many of the current global economic policies and even between rival companies, game theories have often been used to make effective, calculated decisions. A game, in economics, is defined as a situation whereby rules, strategies and payoffs are involved for parties to make beneficial decisions. In this context, of course, “beneficial” is subjective. Why? Let’s take a look at the following example.
The Prisoners’ Dilemma
This classic illustration has been widely used as a simple yet effective explanation of a game theory.
Once upon a time, there were 2 thieves who were caught while trying to steal a car. The Judge decides to sentence them to a 2-year jail term each. However, the Prosecutor suspects that these men were also responsible for an unsolved bank robbery some years back but he lacks concrete evidence that can tie the men to the case. The Prosecutor then devised a plan with the Judge which he hopes would make the thieves confess to their previous crime.
The Prosecutor first places the 2 prisoners in separate rooms so that they cannot communicate with each other. Each is told that they are suspected of an earlier crime and are also told the following:
1. | If each confesses to the robbery, each will get a 3-year jail sentence. |
2. | If 1 person confesses and the other does not, the one who confessed will get only a 1-year sentence while the other will serve 10 years in jail. |
3. | If neither of them confess then each will only be convicted for the car theft and will be sentenced to jail for 2 years. |
If you are one of the prisoners, what would you do?
The payoff matrix is as shown:
Prisoner A’s Strategies | ||||||||||
Prisoner B’s Strategies |
|
Now if I were any of these prisoners, I would be either trying to maximize gain for myself independent of my accomplice’s decision or I would have to make my decision based on how much I trust him. Do I anticipate him to deny so that I can confess and enjoy the shortest of the jail terms? But what if he confesses and I confess as well and my jail term increases to 3 years? So in that case, shall I deny and hope that he denies as well so that we both need only to serve 2 years in jail? But what if he confesses and now I get a 10-year sentence?! Tricky, isn’t it? Hence, the Prisoners’ Dilemma.
The optimum solution to this problem is actually to find its equilibrium. The equilibrium in a game is also known as the Nash equilibrium, named after John Forbes Nash (the character portrayed by Russell Crowe in the movie). This balance occurs when one takes the best possible action given the action of the other party and vice versa. In this example, a dominant strategy exists for each prisoner. This means that in this dilemma, no matter what the other prisoner decides, one would choose to confess because it is the best course of action. Thus, the equilibrium of the prisoners’ dilemma is that each prisoner confesses.
Yes, I know what you’re thinking. Why shouldn’t the equilibrium be the situation if each prisoner denies? If so, both would only serve a 2-year jail sentence compared to a 3-year one right? Take note that the Nash equilibrium is not achieved with actions that would generate the best payoff. Remember the prisoners are kept in separate rooms and trust is an issue here because if I trust that my accomplice would deny along with me, but if he doesn’t, then I am in for a decade behind bars.
This game model is essentially a non-zero sum game, which means that a gain by one player does not necessarily cause a loss in another player. In other words, win-win scenarios exist. On the other hand, there are also zero-sum games, whereby a player gains at the equal expense of other players. An example would be Poker. If I win with a good hand, then I would gain all bets that the other party has made at the table. So with all these “mambo jumbo” about a less-than-interesting economic theory (for some), what does it have to do with organizational behaviour?
Internal Strife
Game theories have been used extensively to study the behaviours of companies in an oligopoly. An oligopoly is a market or industry that is dominated by a few firms. More often than not, the price strategies of these firms are heavily influenced by that of rival firms. An obvious example would be the local petroleum market that is dominated by the likes of Shell and Caltex. Ever noticed that when one of these companies decides to lower its price of petrol, the rest would follow suit? However, the reverse would never happen. Why would any company in an oligopoly be in the right mind to raise prices? Would its rivals follow suit? However, you can try working out a payoff matrix for a hypothetical scenario and you would be able to appreciate the effectiveness of a game theory.
Although several other real-world applications exist, another of a game theory’s application is present as well. One that does not involve comparison between firms but it is one that can help explain the rise of conflicts within an organization.
Have you ever heard or even witness business functions of an organization “backstabbing” one another? Maybe it could be the sales department having constant arguments and disagreements with the production department? Maybe it could also be a case whereby the management fails to work in line with its ground staff? Ever since I became a facilitator, I, personally, have had corporate clients complaining about the friction between one department and another and in some cases, internal competition seems to be the norm as department heads contest with one another, thus putting a huge strain on the entire organization. It has almost gotten pretty cliché with regards to the common troubles that these organizations face. Maybe with an understanding of game theory, “rival” functions within any organization can learn that such conflicts arise from familiar roots.
Let’s say we have a scenario where the product department and the marketing department of a fictitious organization are at loggerheads which each other. The product people are in charge of creating new products while the marketing folks are responsible for selling whatever the product people came up with. However, perhaps due to some misunderstandings and accusations between the two, relationships start to break down and internal strife ensues. The situation gradually escalates to a point whereby both teams must make a decision on whether, they want to cooperate or refuse cooperation with each other. Cooperation here can refer to information-sharing, effective communication etc. Hence the following scenarios, with regards to probable effects each decision has on the organization’s performance as a whole, might just turn out.
1. | If both departments choose to cooperate, each department would contribute $5 million in revenue to the company directly and/or indirectly. |
2. | If one department chooses to cooperate and the other does not, the department that chooses to cooperate would add $7 million to the company’s coffers, while the other contributes $1 million to the organization, whether directly and/or indirectly. |
3. | If both departments choose not to cooperate then each will only contribute $1 million to the company, once again either directly and/or indirectly. |
The payoff matrix is as follows:
Marketing department’s choices | ||||||||||
Production department’s choices |
|
So in this case, what do you think is the Nash equilibrium? In terms of game theory, the Nash equilibrium in this situation would, of course, be the point when both departments cooperate. This is so because no matter what choices that the other department makes, one would choose to cooperate in order to maximize one’s gains. In addition, the organization benefits from the highest total revenue with mutual cooperation, as compared with the rest of the other scenarios. However, would this be the dominant strategy for both departments?
In theory, any business functions within the same organization would decide to cooperate to avoid conflict and at the same time, generate win-win results. However, how often have we witness Scenario D as the eventual outcome? Simply because Scenario B and C, more often than not, do not exist in the real world and the fact is that we live in a “tit-for-tat” society. This is what I call the Pan Disequilibrium. Okay….I’m just kidding. Let’s just name this point as the Organizational Disequilibrium.
Firstly, any CEO would tell you that in situations like this, product folks have to learn to co-exist and collaborate with their marketing counterparts because these two key departments are interdependent with each other. However, if one department refuses to cooperate, do you think the resulting party would not follow suit? Assuming ceteris paribus (all things remaining the same), any person would retaliate in response to hostility towards him or her. Eventually, a “bloodbath” begins, leaving both parties crippled, whilst generating negative results.
Why then do teams degenerate to such a state? We will find the answers in the deeper roots of such organizational relationships. These answers lie with two very tenuous components in relationship-building and you can find them in my earlier pages. The words are highlighted and I’m sure anyone can spot them.
You got them? If you did, then scroll down to the next page to verify your answers. No prizes for getting them correct though.
BINGO!
The two critical factors that determine any positive relationships are:
1. | Communication and |
2. | Trust |
In the Prisoners’ Dilemma, communication was cut off between both prisoners and thus, trust became an issue. This setting then led us to the Nash equilibrium of when both prisoners confess. In the product/marketing analogy, wouldn’t communication be readily available to allow both departments to produce win-win results? Strange isn’t it? In today’s organizational environment, with the widespread availability of communication technologies, why should communication be of any concern? Why, even with communication, our product and marketing teams would still end up in Scenario D?
What is communication?
First of all, let us define communication. According to Dictionary.com, the word “communication” is defined as the imparting or interchange of thoughts, opinions, or information by speech, writing, or signs. However, do you think that communication would be more of an “interchange” instead of an “imparting”? In this case, is sending an e-mail message or posting a notice a form of communication? Is holding an “informative” meeting a form of communication? The answer: no. These are mere forms of notification. Why? Let us take a look at the following model which illustrates the Communication Cycle.
Effective communication entails a
sender to transmit a clear message for a recipient to understand and not just
be heard. Upon receiving the message, the intended recipient would be able to
acknowledge the message and/or provide feedback if need be back to the sender.
Nonetheless, if you agree with me on this specific definition, how many of us
do practice effective communication?
Sometimes? All the time? None at
all? But how important is communication in an organization? This next case
study will demonstrate the significance of organizational communication.
Case Study: The Re-birth of Continental Airlines
The following details the profile of
Continental Airlines, one of the best airline companies in America and the
world currently.
– | No.
1 U.S.-based Airline |
– | Best
Transatlantic Airline |
– | Top
International Airline |
– | Best
Executive/Business Class |
– | Best
U.S. Airline for Business Travel |
– | No.
1 On-time Performance in 2000 |
– | No.
1 Most Admired Airline |
The following details the profile of
Continental Airlines, one of the best airline companies in America and the
world currently, in 1994.
– | Experienced 10 changes in
leadership in 10 years. |
– | Went through bankruptcy
proceedings twice. |
– | Has not made a profit in 10 years. |
– | Customers were shunning the
airline. |
– | Arrival and departure times were
very unpredictable and as the then CEO commented, that their planes “came and
went as they happened to”. |
– | According to the Department of
Transportation, Continental Airlines was ranked last among the country’s 10
biggest airlines. |
– | The company received almost 3
times as many complaints as the industry average and more than 30% more
complaints than the ninth-placed airline. |
During these trying times,
Continental Airlines was undoubtedly THE worst airline in the whole of America.
With abysmal morale, non-existent cooperation among employees and a barrel full
of lies from the management, the company was in total chaos. As then CEO, Gordon
Bethune, once remarked that it was “a company with a lousy product, angry
employees, low wages, and a history of ineffective management.”
Faced with an organization in dire
straits, Bethune knew he had to radically change the company culture and
communication was the key to Continental’s survival and revival. He knew that
positive, healthy interaction was vital in turning things around and
interestingly, the first thing that Bethune did was to open up the executive
offices to all employees.
In the past, the twentieth-storey
office for Continental’s top management in Houston was like a fortress. Its
doors were shut from prying eyes as surveillance cameras prowled the place like
tigers searching for a prey. No one could enter this area without a security pass
and this was not exactly the most inviting place to be for any employee.
However, in a symbolic gesture, Bethune literally opened the once-locked doors
to the entire company. Thereafter, open houses were organized for employees in
order for employee-management barriers to be broken and thus allow trust to,
once again, be built.
Nonetheless, the road to restoration
was not always a smooth-riding one. However, Continental’s leaders kept up with
their regular meetings with their people, as views were aired and shared.
Honesty and patience were a priority as the management revealed everything to
its employees, good news or bad. Bulletin boards were also put up in every
employee area that displayed the company’s ratings for the previous year, as
assessed by the Department of Transportation; and daily company news updates.
Additional forms of communication were also put in place, including monthly and
quarterly employee newsletter which were mailed to each employee’s house and
even 800-number hotlines for any employee to enquire about anything from
anywhere in the world. Bethune’s communication policy was simple: “Unless it’s
dangerous and illegal for us to share it, we share it.”
As weeks become months, slowly but
gradually, Continental finally began to function as a team. In the year that
Bethune took over the reins of CEO, 1994, the company lost US$204 million. By
the end of the next year, Continental posted a profit of US$202 million.
Subsequently, for the next half a decade, Continental posted twenty-four consecutive
profitable quarters in a time when their competitors struggled to remain
afloat.
An Afterword
People often ask, “Why is there a
need for teamwork?” “Why can’t we focus just on ourselves and generate higher
returns?” “Everyone wants to win and for every winner, there will be a loser,
isn’t it?” As human beings, even as employees within a company, we often assume
that we are constantly being engaged in zero-sum games, when in fact non-zero
sum games exist and these should be the mode of operation in order to maximize
gains, both individually and organizationally.
But for a beneficial equilibrium to be achieved, communication is vital. In fact,
effective communication must be present for a borderless team to function well.
If the management of Continental Airlines still persisted with a strict
top-down approach with information flowing through a one-way route, I don’t
think it could turn things around so quickly. If communication barriers are
erected, distrust will permeate through every member, every department; and if
trust becomes an issue, then the organization will, without a sliver of doubt,
slip into a chaotic disequilibrium,
fueled by retaliation. In order to for you to digest this lengthy article easily,
just remember the following three pointers:
1. | For every hostile action, there
will be an equal (sometimes more) and opposite retaliation. |
2. | Communication builds trust and
trust builds successful organizations. |
3. | Do not forget Points (1) and (2) |
So folks…remember to be nice. Being
nice does have its bottom-line benefits as niceness begets niceness as
hostility begets hostility; and if in doubt check with the Game Theory.
References:
1. | Michael Parkin, (1993), “Economics
(Second Edition)”, Addison-Wesley Publshing Company (13 March 2008) |
2. | John C. Maxwell, (2001), “The 17
Indisputable Laws of Teamwork”, Nelson Business (18 March 2008) |
3. | Continental Airlines, (2008),
About Continental > Company Profile > Awards. |